Close

This page had been redirected to a new URL, please update any bookmarks.

Font Size: A A A

macroblog

« What's behind the recent rise in Treasury yields? | Main | Looking back, looking forward »

December 22, 2010

An inflation (or lack thereof) chart show

Over at TheMoneyIllusion, Scott Sumner takes a shot at what he refers to as "Disinflation Denial." His point is that prior to the recent run-up, "commodity price indices fell by more than 50%." Thus, if the run-up in commodity prices suggests loose policy now, they must have been signaling tight policy earlier.

I am hesitant to endorse the view that any subset of prices gives us a clear view of inflation trends. What I do endorse in the Sumner piece is the advice that "the Fed look at a wide range of indicators." I can tell you that is exactly what we do at the Atlanta Reserve Bank and, as just one example within the Fed System, in this post I'll review the battery of indicators that we are currently looking at here. Most of these will be no surprise, but I find it useful to occasionally see them in one place. So here we go. (Note that throughout this blog post I will focus most of my comments on the consumer price index [CPI], but most of what I say also applies to the personal consumption expenditure [PCE] price index as well.)

First up, of course, are the so-called (and often maligned) core measures of inflation. I am completely sympathetic to the view that the traditional core index, which subtracts out food and energy components, is a somewhat arbitrary cut of the price statistics. For that reason, Ipersonally tend to lean more heavily on median and trimmed-mean measures.


In Atlanta, we have been monitoring a newer core inflation measure, called the "sticky-price CPI," jointly developed by Mike Bryan and Brent Meyer (of the Atlanta and Cleveland Feds, respectively). As described by Bryan and Meyer:

"Some of the items that make up the Consumer Price Index change prices frequently, while others are slow to change… sticky prices [those that are slow to change] appear to incorporate expectations about future inflation to a greater degree than prices that change on a frequent basis… our sticky-price measure seems to contain a component of inflation expectations, and that component may be useful when trying to gauge where inflation is heading."

Like the other core measure, the sticky-price CPI shows a pronounced downward movement over the past several years, with some sign of (an ever-so-slight) recovery as of late.


Though I disagree with the assertion that core measures are a convenient way to ignore unpleasant movements in the overall CPI—there is evidence that core measures are useful in predicting where total CPI inflation is heading—it is almost surely a bad idea to ignore what is happening to headline statistics. (After all, in the end it is the average of all prices with which we are concerned.)

Here too, the evidence suggests, at the very least, there is scant evidence that disinflation has left the scene:


I find it useful to take at least two more cuts at the overall price data. One, which has a decidedly short-term focus, involves examining the distribution of price changes in the broad categories that make up the headline CPI. Though a popular criticism of Fed policy—discussed and critiqued at Econbrowser—tries to deflate deflation concerns by reciting a number of prices that are rising, it is obvious that one could just as easily tick off a reasonably large list of prices that are falling:


(The individual colors in the chart represent different components of the CPI. The underlying data can be found from this link to the explanation of the median CPI.)

The graph of the November price change distribution is actually somewhat encouraging. What it tells us is that almost half of the price changes in the CPI market basket, weighted by their shares of total consumer expenditures, fell in the (annualized) range of 0 percent to 2 percent. Furthermore, about as many price changes were below this range as they were above it.

A closer look at the prices that fall in the 0 percent to 2 percent category, however, reveals that individual price changes are skewed to the downside of the range:


On a month-to-month basis, the distribution of individual prices does shift around, so these statistics are nothing more than suggestive short-run snapshots (but I believe they are informative nonetheless).

At the other end of the temporal scale is a look at how inflation has behaved over time. If the central bank had a long history of missing its stated inflation objectives, we might feel very different about an inflation rate that is below what Chairman Bernanke has referred to as "the mandate-consistent inflation rate" of "about 2 percent or a bit below" than we would if average prices were hewing pretty close to the target path. As I have previously noted, over the past 15 years or so, the Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC) has delivered an average inflation rate, measured as growth in the PCE price index, that is wholly consistent with this mandate. Here's the case in a graph, adjusting the mandate-consistent inflation rate to account for an assumed upward bias in the CPI relative to the PCE index:


Actually, those short-run complications are mostly associated with falling expectations of inflation. In my last macroblog post, I argued that the stabilization of market-based CPI inflation expectations and the associated decline in the perceived probability of deflation should arguably be counted as a success of the Fed's current policy stance. The latest on market-based expectations was included in our previous macroblog item. For completeness, survey-based expected long-term inflation remains somewhat below the levels prior to the onset of the recession:


I believe this is basically the bottom line: whether we look at headline inflation (straight-up, component-by-component, or in terms of the long-run trend), core inflation measures (of virtually any sensible variety), or inflation expectations (survey or market based), there is little a hint of building inflationary pressure.

While I don't dismiss the usefulness of looking at other indicators (stock prices, bond prices, foreign exchange rates, commodity prices, and real estate prices are on Scott Sumner's list; I would add various measures of labor costs to mine), you have to be pretty selective in your attentions to build the contrary case.

But feel free. We'll keep watching.

Photo of Dave Altig By Dave Altig
Senior vice president and research director at the Atlanta Fed

December 22, 2010 in Deflation, Inflation | Permalink

TrackBack

TrackBack URL for this entry:
http://www.typepad.com/services/trackback/6a00d8341c834f53ef0148c6fa5c32970c

Listed below are links to blogs that reference An inflation (or lack thereof) chart show:

Comments

Can the Federal government afford ANY inflation? Isn't the FED playing with fire, when we can clearly see the massive liabilities directly ahead?
Commodity inflation helps Canada and Australia but is suicide for the US, since the middle east is slowly easing away from the dollar.
The only card the US has left is the dollar, it should be defending it as though it's life depends on it........it does!
The best case scenario for the US is a Japanese style low growth, low interest rate environment. Over promised pension and health care liabilities need to correct to their viable level. Pushing the dollar carry trade is creating massive gambling and we know how that will turn out.
As Chuck Prince said, as long as the music is playing, you gotta get up and dance....the US cannot afford the fallout when the music stops. The next bust takes down the system. Pension fund gambling will probably be the trigger for the coming meltdown.

Posted by: Groucho | December 24, 2010 at 09:17 AM

a lot of people fanning the inflation fears are pointing to the softs; sugar, coffee, cocoa and cotton. However, they had bad crop years. Next years crop prices right now are considerably lower.

However, meat and grain prices for next year are higher than this year.

Demographics also point to less domestic inflation. As populations age, they demand less in terms of durable goods etc.
The US population is aging.

It's a cloudy picture for sure. The one axiom that I think you should be able to hang your hat on is that there will be little inflation without employment improving.

Posted by: Jeff | December 26, 2010 at 03:35 PM

"Afford" inflation? We can't afford not to have inflation! We need more inflation to stimulate the economy and reduce the value of existing debts.

Posted by: Beet | January 01, 2011 at 07:21 PM

The short term prices like grain for feed and planting have long term implications. Russian wheat contracts driving the feed lot prices off the charts have not been priced in at the end user yet the consumer will be paying a lot more for that steak or burger until all the cattle and hogs are sold eaten or we all start eating carrots. How on earth can the government spend and print spend and print without the slippery slope taking over just like it did in the 70's. I remember the gas lines and int. rates of 18% at the bank on CD's and I think Mr. Greenspan does too!

Posted by: David Sobel | January 06, 2011 at 11:58 PM

Post a comment

Comments are moderated and will not appear until the moderator has approved them.

If you have a TypeKey or TypePad account, please Sign in